ֱ̽ of Cambridge - Vincent Mak /taxonomy/people/vincent-mak en How to get teams to share information /research/news/how-to-get-teams-to-share-information <div class="field field-name-field-news-image field-type-image field-label-hidden"><div class="field-items"><div class="field-item even"><img class="cam-scale-with-grid" src="/sites/default/files/styles/content-580x288/public/news/research/news/people-coffee-notes-tea.png?itok=j1dAVViy" alt="" title="Credit: None" /></div></div></div><div class="field field-name-body field-type-text-with-summary field-label-hidden"><div class="field-items"><div class="field-item even"><p> ֱ̽study reveals that teams across the land are not playing nicely after all. In fact, there are many occasions when we choose not to share information with colleagues if we think it can harm our own prospects of success. And when that information determines, say, the level of funding passed down from a CEO, it can have a significant – and counter-productive – effect on the company as a whole.</p>&#13; &#13; <p>“Most organisations must make decisions about where best to allocate resources,” said Nektarios (Aris) Oraiopoulos of Cambridge Judge Business School, whose <a href="http://pubsonline.informs.org/doi/10.1287/mnsc.2014.2083" target="_blank">study</a>, published in the journal <em>Management Science</em>, examined how these issues play out in the pharmaceutical industry. “Pharmaceutical companies as a whole need to regularly reassess their research and development portfolios and decide which projects have the greatest potential; for example they might choose to improve an existing drug or develop a new one. Such decisions are often made by executives who rely on information provided by the project managers. But individual project managers do not necessarily give accurate information to the boss if they think it will cost them the resources that fund their projects.”</p>&#13; &#13; <p>Oraiopoulos’s study, undertaken with Vincent Mak of Cambridge Judge Business School, and Professor Jochen Schlapp of Mannheim ֱ̽, revealed managers’ likelihood to share information depended on whether there was an appropriate fit between the type of the project (e.g. a new project vs a ‘me-too’ project) and the incentives scheme in place.</p>&#13; &#13; <p>“In small companies such as start-ups, there’s often such a strong culture of collective ambition and responsibility – and enhanced risk – that it’s hard to attribute success or failure individually,” said Oraiopoulos. “Therefore the most effective incentive rewards everyone on the basis of the collective success. But as the company grows, people inevitably assume singular responsibilities, the outcomes are less risky and, in the interests of the company, managers start following individual agendas – and management starts rewarding individual performance.”</p>&#13; &#13; <p>Which is where the problems start. “If two project managers are offered a group incentive for success, individuals are more willing to be upfront about any failings. But when the two project managers compete for resources and rewards, as it often happens in a bigger organisation, project managers are less likely to step aside.”</p>&#13; &#13; <p>There are many reasons for this, said Oraiopoulos, not necessarily based in deception. “Pharmaceutical research includes many ‘true believers’ – researchers who have absolute faith in a new product, especially if it could cure an important disease. But that faith skews their judgment. They believe their breakthrough is just around the corner, even if all the existing evidence suggests otherwise.”</p>&#13; &#13; <p>This is a difficult moral argument for any CEO to reject – a difficulty compounded by the lack of impartial information in such a knowledge-specific industry. “One project manager’s specialty might be cardiovascular, another’s oncology,” said Oraiopoulos. “No one knows the science and potential of their product better than they do. They can present an accurate case on why their project deserves resources – or, consciously or subconsciously, mask its failings because no-one has the expertise to challenge them. So how does the CEO tell the difference?”</p>&#13; &#13; <p> ֱ̽answer is trust and giving teams a compelling motivation to be honest. But a collective incentive has drawbacks. “If you’re leading one of five departments who are rewarded only for collective excellence,” said Oraiopoulos, “where’s your motivation? You might as well let the others carry you.”</p>&#13; &#13; <p>And even financial incentive doesn’t necessarily work. “Many researchers’ greatest reward is completing their project,” said Oraiopoulos. “That means being consistently confident their boss supports their work.”</p>&#13; &#13; <p>So what’s the solution? “Organisations are tackling it in different ways,” he said. “Some are creating smaller, individual units, for example, centres of excellence or turning departments into small start-ups, with defined budgets. Others are promoting more collaboration between departments.”</p>&#13; &#13; <p>Swiss global healthcare company Roche did both. When it bought drug developer Genentech in 2009 it kept the two companies’ research and development sections separate, empowering its “late-stage development group” to pick the strongest project – and motivating the losing group by announcing it would develop its plans later. But while that worked with Alzheimer’s treatments, a more linked approach was required for fast-paced developments in cancer research. “ ֱ̽need to understand the biology and right therapeutic approach requires the best minds,” said Roche’s head of oncology Jason Coloma. “We needed to leverage the knowledge in these divisions and break down some of these firewalls.”</p>&#13; &#13; <p> ֱ̽company formed a cancer immunotherapy committee which, says Roche, “brings the leadership and senior scientific minds together to consider different areas of interest and unmet needs that can be fulfilled by looking at different combinations.”</p>&#13; &#13; <p>Roche’s approach confirms Oraiopoulos’s findings that new products require a team strategy, while ‘me-too’ projects benefit from more individual approaches. But how to break down a colossal R&amp;D function into start-up-style divisions?</p>&#13; &#13; <p>GlaxoSmithKline replaced its research and development ‘pyramid’ with 12 centres of excellence. “We learned these centres must be built around two things,” its then CEO Jean-Pierre Garnier said later. “A specific mission – the most effective therapies for Alzheimer’s – and the stage of the R&amp;D process required to perform that mission, for example choosing a target for attacking the disease. Anything not critical to the core R&amp;D process must occur outside the centre. All other functions – toxicology, drug metabolism, formulation, had to become service units, delivering at the lowest possible cost.”</p>&#13; &#13; <p>Simultaneously, GSK overhauled its incentives. “Pharmaceutical R&amp;D typically pursues two objectives – to be first in class and to offer the best-in-class compound for attacking a disease. For too long the industry has tried to be a ballet dancer and a footballer at the same time.”</p>&#13; &#13; <p>But he warned fragmenting a company needs commitment. “To operate in this fashion, companies must strengthen opportunities, negotiate deals and nurture external scientific ‘bets’ (work with outside experts). This means a cultural shift. It’s an enormous but necessary task.”</p>&#13; &#13; <p>Oraiopoulos’s research suggests there are so many variables – different products, motivations, branches of medicine, organisational goals – each company must then find its own solution. Pfizer’s recent buy-out of Botox maker Allergan is expected to maintain separate divisions for innovative and established treatments, so how the company allocates its resources remains to be seen.</p>&#13; &#13; <p>“You must strike a balance,” said Oraiopoulos, “between rewarding individual and group performance. It’s a spectrum and each company must find their place on it, for patients and for the advancement of treatments. Many companies are encountering this challenge. We’re only scratching the surface.”</p>&#13; &#13; <p><em><strong>Reference:</strong><br />&#13; Schlapp, Oraiopoulos, and Mak: '<a href="http://pubsonline.informs.org/doi/10.1287/mnsc.2014.2083" target="_blank">Resource Allocation Under Imperfect Evaluation</a>.' Management Science (2015). DOI: 10.1287/mnsc.2014.2083</em></p>&#13; &#13; <p><em>Originally published on the Cambridge Judge Business School <a href="https://www.jbs.cam.ac.uk/2016/information-is-power-heres-what-to-do-to-get-your-team-to-share-information-better/">website</a>. </em></p>&#13; </div></div></div><div class="field field-name-field-content-summary field-type-text-with-summary field-label-hidden"><div class="field-items"><div class="field-item even"><p><p>Are you happy to share information with your colleagues? And do they share their valuable information with you? A number of companies have realised that withholding key information within organisational silos might happen more often that we might like to admit. Now a new study suggests how and when companies should restore meaningful communication across the organisation.</p>&#13; </p></div></div></div><div class="field field-name-field-cc-attribute-text field-type-text-long field-label-hidden"><div class="field-items"><div class="field-item even"><p><a href="http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/" rel="license"><img alt="Creative Commons License" src="https://i.creativecommons.org/l/by/4.0/88x31.png" style="border-width:0" /></a><br />&#13; ֱ̽text in this work is licensed under a <a href="http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/" rel="license">Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License</a>. For image use please see separate credits above.</p>&#13; </div></div></div><div class="field field-name-field-show-cc-text field-type-list-boolean field-label-hidden"><div class="field-items"><div class="field-item even">Yes</div></div></div> Fri, 22 Jan 2016 08:00:00 +0000 sc604 165682 at Digital bargain hunters: optimal online searching /research/news/digital-bargain-hunters-optimal-online-searching <div class="field field-name-field-news-image field-type-image field-label-hidden"><div class="field-items"><div class="field-item even"><img class="cam-scale-with-grid" src="/sites/default/files/styles/content-580x288/public/news/research/news/150506-bargains.gif?itok=eQ6QgZ9N" alt="Bargains Galore!" title="Bargains Galore!, Credit: Roadsidepictures" /></div></div></div><div class="field field-name-body field-type-text-with-summary field-label-hidden"><div class="field-items"><div class="field-item even"><p>A ‘sunk cost’ is a cost that has already been incurred previously and can’t be recovered – in this case that means the time and effort that has been expended trawling the internet for deals.</p>&#13; &#13; <p>There is always a trade-off between the potential of getting a better deal by searching more, and the time and effort involved in searching. ֱ̽study, “Culture Moderates Biases in Search Decisions”, which has been accepted for publication in a forthcoming issue of the journal <em>Psychological Science,</em> found that Easterners tend to search more than they should following prior extensive search efforts.</p>&#13; &#13; <p><img alt="Vincent Mak" src="/sites/www.cam.ac.uk/files/inner-images/150506_dr-vincent-mak.jpg" style="float:right; height:250px; line-height:20.7999992370605px; width:250px" /></p>&#13; &#13; <p>“We found that Easterners search longer than the cost-effective benchmark when search costs become high, but not Westerners,” said Vincent Mak, ֱ̽ Lecturer in Marketing &amp; Decision Sciences at Cambridge Judge Business School, who has also conducted several other detailed behavioural studies concerning online search.</p>&#13; &#13; <p>In academic terms, search is a form of sequential decision making for which there is an optimal stopping point. Beyond this point, the further effort of hitting the ‘search’ button once again is not worth the potential for finding a better deal.</p>&#13; &#13; <p>“As search costs accumulate, Easterners become more ‘obsessed’ than Westerners with getting a really good deal to justify all the effort spent,” added Mak, a native of Hong Kong.</p>&#13; &#13; <p> ֱ̽study involved hundreds of university students at Cambridge ֱ̽ and Chulalongkorn ֱ̽ in Bangkok, Thailand. It was co-authored by Mak and Jake Pattaratanakun, a Thai native who is a PhD student at Cambridge Judge as well as a lecturer in Marketing at Chulalongkorn ֱ̽.</p>&#13; &#13; <p>Although the research focuses on students in the UK and Thailand, the authors believe that the cultural characteristics central to the study also apply more broadly to other Easterners and Westerners.</p>&#13; &#13; <p>Mak conjectures that the findings could reflect previous research showing that Easterners may be more prone to take risk when financial gains (such as potentially better price deals) are involved. Because ‘sunk costs’ represent a loss, this drives risk-taking people to try to recoup losses through additional searching in the face of uncertainty.</p>&#13; &#13; <p> ֱ̽study involved the online purchase of a virtual product with a known value of 700 tokens and a price quote that was randomly generated by each search within controlled deviations. There was a cost associated with each sequential search – starting at five tokens and then increasing in multiples of five tokens in subsequent searches. So each participant’s net payoff was 700 tokens minus both the purchase price obtained and all accumulated search costs.</p>&#13; &#13; <p>To test the assumption that it is cultural differences that drive Easterners to over-search when ‘sunk costs’ are high, the study checked whether language used in the study may be able to skew results by “switching on” subjects’ cultural mindset. ֱ̽experiment was repeated with Thai students from a bilingual, bicultural background.</p>&#13; &#13; <p>This time, purchase patterns of the Thai students participating in English were “largely the same” as UK students – but the patterns were “markedly different”, with participants undertaking longer searches before making a purchase, when the bicultural participants conducted the experiment in their Thai language.</p>&#13; &#13; <p> ֱ̽study also further tested whether awareness of the ‘sunk costs’ of their searches influenced participants’ behaviour. While earlier testing rounds told all participants of their accumulated search costs, additional tests did not inform participants of these ‘sunk costs’ – and found that in this case purchase patterns were largely the same between Eastern and Western participants.</p>&#13; &#13; <p>“This observation is consistent with our premise that ‘sunk cost’ effects are a key driver of the cross-cultural differences in biases in search decisions,” the study concluded.</p>&#13; &#13; <p><em>Inset image: Dr Vincent Mak.</em></p>&#13; &#13; <p><em>Article originally published by <a href="https://www.jbs.cam.ac.uk/2015/optimal-online-searching/">Cambridge Judge Business School</a>.</em></p>&#13; </div></div></div><div class="field field-name-field-content-summary field-type-text-with-summary field-label-hidden"><div class="field-items"><div class="field-item even"><p><p>Easterners are more inclined than Westerners to search too long online for the best deals because they are more sensitive to the ‘sunk cost’ of their previous search efforts, according to a study from Cambridge Judge Business School.</p>&#13; </p></div></div></div><div class="field field-name-field-content-quote field-type-text-long field-label-hidden"><div class="field-items"><div class="field-item even">As search costs accumulate, Easterners become more ‘obsessed’ than Westerners with getting a really good deal to justify all the effort spent</div></div></div><div class="field field-name-field-content-quote-name field-type-text field-label-hidden"><div class="field-items"><div class="field-item even">Vincent Mak</div></div></div><div class="field field-name-field-image-credit field-type-link-field field-label-hidden"><div class="field-items"><div class="field-item even"><a href="https://www.flickr.com/photos/roadsidepictures/3896644731/in/photolist-6WkjHR-2jPuE8-4n5iSD-pGzesb-dqKJX4-8W95JM-fC8V9P-47qjVC-eyiB58-aTLbJZ-99ojWG-e1r5sk-j3bRb2-hkKGwD-7kUVPP-2ZJFFB-mEP3R-jXy2Mn-92qsfM-i5ZGKs-azN8kq-8fsvmJ-7EuWio-4nzTsL-9gcNZP-ncG3wV-bEoaW8-eyizQn-p3uaec-dYwEQn-5jrueZ-fjVNf6-8hX5QR-4xbrMk-dkBgrC-dkBgiC-Z5PAa-7te4c-dkBeEi-Z5Pyc-4uEuxu-fnBw57-pYoB9W-fnnkc4-bXUD2G-5m9pfx-7dEeqM-4XPjU7-86MVzL-p3sLqQ" target="_blank">Roadsidepictures</a></div></div></div><div class="field field-name-field-image-desctiprion field-type-text field-label-hidden"><div class="field-items"><div class="field-item even">Bargains Galore!</div></div></div><div class="field field-name-field-cc-attribute-text field-type-text-long field-label-hidden"><div class="field-items"><div class="field-item even"><p><a href="https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/" rel="license"><img alt="Creative Commons License" src="https://i.creativecommons.org/l/by/4.0/88x31.png" style="border-width:0" /></a><br />&#13; ֱ̽text in this work is licensed under a <a href="https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/" rel="license">Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License</a>. For image use please see separate credits above.</p>&#13; </div></div></div><div class="field field-name-field-show-cc-text field-type-list-boolean field-label-hidden"><div class="field-items"><div class="field-item even">Yes</div></div></div><div class="field field-name-field-license-type field-type-taxonomy-term-reference field-label-above"><div class="field-label">Licence type:&nbsp;</div><div class="field-items"><div class="field-item even"><a href="/taxonomy/imagecredit/attribution-noncommercial-sharealike">Attribution-Noncommercial-ShareAlike</a></div></div></div> Wed, 06 May 2015 15:42:07 +0000 jeh98 150792 at